Skip Navigation U.S. Department of Health and Human Services www.hhs.gov/
Agency for Healthcare Research Quality www.ahrq.gov
www.ahrq.gov/

Impact of State Laws Limiting Malpractice Awards on Geographic Distribution of Physicians


By Fred J. Hellinger, Ph.D* and William E. Encinosa, Ph.D.*

* U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, Center for Organization and Delivery Studies, 540 Gaither Road, Room 5319, Rockville Maryland 20850. Phone: (301) 427-1408; Fax: (301) 427-1430; E-mail:  FHelling@ahrq.gov

Select to download print version (PDF File, 234 KB). Plugin Software Help.


Contents

Abstract
Introduction
Background
Methodology
Results
Discussion
References

Abstract

Researchers at the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (AHRQ) have examined the impact of different kinds of State laws in a number of previous studies.  This study examines the impact of State legislation that caps damage awards in malpractice cases on decisions of physicians about where to practice medicine.

Twenty-four States now have laws that limit damage payments in malpractice cases.  Most of these laws limit the amounts paid for noneconomic damages (e.g., pain and suffering) but a few limit both economic (e.g., medical expenses and lost wages) and noneconomic damages.  There is currently a national debate on the desirability of extending caps on malpractice damage awards to all States, and President Bush recently introduced a proposal to cap payments for noneconomic damages in medical malpractice cases at $250,000.

Supporters of legislation to cap damages in malpractice cases maintain that it reduces malpractice premiums and helps insure an adequate supply of physicians.  They also assert that escalating, multi-million-dollar jury awards are driving malpractice premium increases and that capping damage awards for pain and suffering helps restrain the rate of increase.  Without such a law, it is asserted that the loss of affordable medical malpractice insurance for physicians could eventually lead to the loss of affordable, accessible health care.  Opponents of this legislation maintain that insurance companies are trying to compensate for poor business decisions and fading investment income.

Although there is some evidence in the literature demonstrating that physicians in States with tort reform laws capping malpractice awards enjoy lower malpractice premiums, there is no evidence about the impact of malpractice cap legislation on decisions by physicians regarding geographic location.  This study is the first to supply such evidence.

A simple comparison of the supply of physicians per capita between States that did and did not adopt a cap revealed that States with caps experienced a more rapid increase in their supply of physicians.  In 1970, before any States had a law capping damage payments in malpractice cases, States that eventually adopted a cap and States that did not eventually adopt a cap had virtually identical levels of physicians per 100,000 citizens per county (69 vs. 67). Thirty years later in 2000, States that adopted a cap averaged 135 physicians per 100,000 citizens per county while States without a cap averaged 120.

Adjusting for a variety of factors in a multivariate regression model, we found that States with caps on noneconomic damages experienced about 12 percent more physicians per capita than States without such a cap.  Moreover, we found that States with relatively high caps were less likely to experience an increase in physician supply than States with lower caps.

Return to Contents

Introduction

In recent months, physicians in New Jersey, West Virginia, and Florida have conducted work stoppages in response to the rapid increases in malpractice insurance premiums and in support of legislation limiting payments for noneconomic damages in malpractice cases.1,2 Malpractice premium rates for internists, general surgeons, and obstetrician/gynecologists increased 25 percent, 25 percent, and 20 percent, respectively, in 2002;3 and last year, legislation limiting noneconomic damage awards in malpractice cases was signed into law in Nevada and Mississippi. 

This year bills limiting noneconomic damage awards in malpractice cases have been signed into law in Ohio and in Texas.4,5,6     There are now 24 States that have a law that caps noneconomic damages or a law that limits total damages: Alaska, California, Colorado, Hawaii, Idaho, Indiana, Kansas, Louisiana, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Mississippi, Missouri, Montana, Nevada, New Mexico, North Dakota, Ohio, South Dakota, Texas, Utah, Virginia, West Virginia, and Wisconsin.

We include States that limit total damages only (Indiana, Louisiana, and Virginia), as well as Colorado, which has a law that imposes separate limits on economic and noneconomic damages, and New Mexico, which has a law that limits total damages less punitive damages and medical expenses.

Proponents of tort reform maintain that the size and frequency of large jury awards and settlements in medical malpractice cases is behind the rapid increase in malpractice insurance premiums and that legislation limiting damage awards is necessary to stem these increases.  They also maintain that high malpractice rates are driving physicians out of business or to States where there is legislation capping malpractice awards.7,8,9

The market for medical malpractice insurance is volatile, and there have been numerous "crises" in this market over the past three decades.10 In response to a crisis in the early 1970s, California passed the Medical Injury Compensation Reform Act of 1975 (MICRA) limiting noneconomic damages in medical malpractice cases.  MICRA is often cited as a model for State legislation. Research has shown that between 1975 and 2000, malpractice premiums grew more slowly in California than they did in the rest of the Nation (167 percent vs. 505 percent).11

A recent publication of the American Medical Association (AMA) discusses the determinants of professional liability insurance (PLI) rates:12

"The increase in the frequency and amount of very large awards may be one of the significant drivers of the rapid escalation in PLI costs. If this is true, then one would expect, over time, that PLI rates in states that have effective damage caps would diverge from the PLI rates in states that have effective tort reform."

There is a sizable body of economic literature demonstrating that the legal environment in a State affects the frequency of malpractice claims and the size of the awards.13   For examples, Zuckerman, Bovbjerg, and Sloan demonstrated that physicians in States with caps on damages in malpractice cases experience lower premiums than physicians in States without such laws.14  Danzon found that damage awards in States with caps on damages were 23 percent lower than in States without caps.15

In another article, Kessler and McClellan examined the impact of tort reforms on the practice of defensive medicine and found that tort reforms such as reasonable limits on noneconomic damages, which have been in effect in California for 25 years, can reduce health care costs by 5 percent to 9 percent without substantial effects on mortality or medical complications.16 Proponents of tort reform legislation emphasize that only 28 percent of physician payments for malpractice insurance are allotted to patients and that the remaining 72 percent are consumed by administrative and related costs.17

Opponents of tort reform legislation that caps damage awards in malpractice cases maintain that poor quality and poor investments by insurance companies are to blame for the recent spike in malpractice rates.  They argue that caps will harm those patients who suffer the most damage and who need help the most, and that payments for medical malpractice claims are not the underlying cause of rapidly increasing malpractice premiums. A recent article states:

"According to the Consumer Federation of America, the average pay-out by medical malpractice insurance companies is about $30,000 per claim and has been virtually unchanged for the last decade."18   

Although there is little agreement about the underlying causes of increases in malpractice premium rates, there is little dispute that rapidly increasing malpractice premium rates have mobilized physicians and engendered considerable support for legislation limiting malpractice damage awards.19 Increasing rates for malpractice premiums and calls for tort reform coincide with increasing concerns about access to care.  A recent BlueCross/BlueShield publication adds:

"What is not in dispute is that the medical liability problem has gained prominence at a time when public concerns about access to care and the cost of that care have re-emerged with new strength."20 

Supporters of legislation capping malpractice damage awards maintain that this legislation is necessary to assure adequate access to health care. One newspaper article points out:21

"The American Medical Association says patients' access to care already is seriously threatened in a dozen states and a crisis is looming in seven others because of rising premiums for malpractice insurance."

A 2003 report by the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services has stated:

"Increasingly, Americans are at risk of not being able to find a doctor when they most need one.  Doctors have given up their practices, limited their practices to patients who do not have health conditions that are more likely to lead to lawsuits, or have moved to states with a fairer legal system where insurance can be obtained at a lower price."22  

And, last year another article reported:

"Nationally, medical liability insurance rates have skyrocketed with several states facing a meltdown of their health care system as a result.  In the states with the fastest-growing rates, doctors have begun 'running bare', without insurance coverage, or have left the state altogether."23 

Return to Contents

Background

Two types of liability are germane to this study: contract and tort.24,25,26 Contracts are voluntary agreements entered into for significant benefit between parties, and contract liability involves implementing the provision of contracts.  Contracts specify in detail the services that will be afforded, and the liabilities created by contracts are limited to the cost of the services specified in the contract (e.g., there are no punitive damages for breach of contract or liability for unanticipated outcomes following the breach of contract).  This certitude and the limited liability required under contracts have been an effective mechanism by which to assist fruitful relationships among distinct contributors in our economic system, and courts have been hesitant to void the provisions of contracts between consenting parties. 

Torts are civil wrongs where the injured person asks for monetary damages from an individual in a situation where there is no contractual relationship.  Tort law sets in place public procedures about how people and businesses are anticipated to act toward one another.  Most people who are engaged in a "learned profession" may be sued in tort for malpractice (e.g., negligence claims by patients against their physicians for malpractice are tort claims).  Compensation in malpractice cases may consist of expenses for all harm endured by the patient counting medical care costs, lost wages, pain, and suffering, as well as punitive payments in situations where there was malicious intent. 

Return to Contents

Methodology

The theoretical structure underlying the empirical analysis in this study is that one of the factors taken into consideration by physicians in selecting a site to practice is the market for medical malpractice insurance.27 In particular, it is hypothesized that physicians are more likely to settle in a State with a law that limits their exposure to malpractice damage awards. 

One recent newspaper article maintains:

"On a much broader level, it the litigation crisis] brought new attention to a national problem that doctors say is obliging many of them to flee certain states or give up certain specialties—or the entire profession—because of skyrocketing insurance premiums linked to soaring jury awards."28

And another adds:

"Yet while the doctors will be the ones to feel the pain first, it is the patients who will do the real suffering, perhaps, in the form of higher fees, and in declining health care as more doctors hang up their surgical gowns."29

Our model presupposes that factors affecting the demand for physician services also affect the geographic distribution of physicians.  For example, recent research has shown that economic development measured by per capita income is positively correlated with physician supply across a variety of countries.30 In our study, we presume that States with higher personal incomes are more desirable locations in which to practice because they have a higher demand for health services, and this, in turn, will result in higher physician incomes and a greater supply of physicians.  For this reason, we include personal income in our model. 

Similarly, we presume that States with higher unemployment rates are likely to have a lower demand for health services and this will result in lower physician incomes. As a result, we include a State's unemployment rate in our model.

Because of the longer distances involved in seeing patients and the relative scarcity of health care resources, it is assumed that physicians will be more likely to settle in more densely populated areas.  In discussing States where physicians have a problem in obtaining affordable malpractice insurance, a recent newspaper article maintains:

"Larger malpractice claims mean higher insurance premiums and more money for trial lawyers. They also mean fewer doctors, particularly in the states most affected. Within those states, the hardest hit communities are rural, where a doctor's income is not enough to offset higher premiums. Those doctors will leave the small towns for the cities, leave the state for a more friendly environment or simply quit practicing."31

For this reason, we include a variable that measures the number of citizens (measured in thousands) per square mile for each State.  Older persons have a greater demand for health care services than younger citizens due to the increased frequency of illness.  Moreover, persons over the age of 65 are almost always covered by Medicare.  Thus, it is hypothesized herein that physicians will be more likely to settle in areas with relatively high proportions of elderly citizens.  Consequently, this study includes a variable that measures the proportion of each State's population that is 65 years or older.

The proportion of persons working on farms is assumed to be negatively related to the demand for health services.  Farm workers are more likely to lack insurance and receive low wages and thus are expected to have little disposable income to spend on health care services.  Consequently, a variable measuring the percentage of the State domestic product (i.e., a measure of the value of goods and services produced within a State) attributable to farm activities is included in the model.

This study estimates the impact of State laws limiting damage awards in malpractice cases on physician availability first using statewide aggregate data and then using county data.  Physician availability is measured by the number of active, non-Federal physicians practicing in each State per 100,000 population using data provided by the AMA.  The primary independent variable of interest is set equal to 1 if the State has a law that limits the level of damage awards and zero otherwise. That is, this variable is set equal to 1 for the 19 States listed in Table 1A (excluding Alaska).

The aforementioned variables are utilized in the analyses based on State data.  The State-level analyses are conducted on State characteristics at four points in time: 1985, 1990, 1995, and 2000.  To test the robustness of these State-level analyses, we perform an additional analysis at the county level for the final 5 years (1996-2000) using two additional control variables available for these years of county data. 

First, in our county-level analyses, we use a variable set equal to 1 if a county has a hospital with a physician residency training program, and we hypothesize that this variable has a positive coefficient because medical residents are more likely to settle in areas where they have trained.  We do not use this variable in the State-level analyses because every State has at least one hospital with a residency program.

Second, in the county-level analysis, we are able to control for the county's health maintenance organization (HMO) enrollment. We use a variable set equal to 1 if the county has high HMO penetration (an HMO enrollment above 30 percent) at the midpoint of the 5-year period: 1998. We hypothesize that physician availability will be lower for counties with high HMO penetration since HMOs tend to restrict patient access to doctors through closed networks.  We do not use this variable in the State-level analyses because of the high correlation between population per square mile and HMO penetration.

Physician availability is measured by the number of active, non-Federal physicians practicing in each county per 100,000 population.  In addition, in the county analysis, we derive a measure of rural influence from a variable constructed by the U.S. Department of Agriculture that is available in the Area Resource File (ARF).  We hypothesize that this variable, which we refer to as "ruralness," is negatively related to the supply of physicians.  

We also use a variable measuring the number of births per capita in each county.  This variable measures the youthfulness of the population, and we hypothesize that it will have a negative coefficient in our equations.

A variable measuring the unemployment rate in each county also is included.  However, we do not utilize a variable that measures the proportion of income attributable to farm activities because this information is not readily available for counties. 

Finally, we also include a variable that is set equal to 1 if the county has an average annual temperature of 70 degrees or higher. We hypothesize that doctors may tend to set up practice in temperate climates of the country.  Moreover, the elderly tend to retire to these areas, and they require a greater level of physician services.

We estimate our model using State data and then county data because these approaches have offsetting strengths and weaknesses.  The empirical analyses utilizing State data provide information about the effectiveness of State laws limiting damage awards on the supply of physicians in each State. And, because we are interested in ascertaining the impact of State laws on physician supply in a State, the use of the State as a unit of observation is reasonable. However, models using State data provide a relatively blunt instrument to assess the impact of a law that limits payments for damages in medical malpractice cases because this approach obscures the impact of variables within specific markets within a State. 

Analyses based on county data include information about counties with different characteristics within each State.  Thus, analyses based on county data can tell us whether a county with a hospital that has a residency program has a larger supply of physicians than a county without such a hospital.   

Moreover, the use of county data may be more appropriate than State data to the extent that the impact of specific variables is felt within each county rather than within each State.  For example, the unemployment rate of each county (as opposed to the unemployment rate in the State) may be a better measure of the impact of unemployment on physician supply in a given county than the unemployment rate in the State.  However, in cases where the market for physician care extends beyond a county's border, the use of the county as the unit of observation may distort estimates of the impact of the law.

Adjusting for the simultaneous impact of multiple factors (i.e., independent variables including the existence of a State law limiting malpractice damage awards) on the dependent variable is accomplished using multivariate linear regression analysis. 

Coefficients for the independent variables in our multivariate linear regression analysis are estimated using least-squares estimators (i.e., the estimated coefficients are obtained so that they result in the lowest sums of squares of the differences between the actual and estimated value of the dependent variable).  This model is estimated under the usual assumptions that the relationship between the dependent and the independent variables is linear and that the error term is normally distributed.32 

The robust standard errors in the county analysis are heteroskedasticity-consistent and are corrected for clustering at the county level.   Influential outliers were removed from the county data: about 30 counties were dropped since they were coded with either less than 10 doctors per 100,000 residents or over 1,000 doctors per 100,000 residents. This was less than 1 percent of the county sample.

Data

Information about State medical liability laws was obtained from the National Conference of State Legislatures (NCSL),33 the American Tort Reform Association (ATRA),34 and from publications of a large law firm.35   The NCSL provides a listing by State of all State medical liability laws that includes the type of reform implemented (e.g., limit on economic and noneconomic damage awards) and the specific legislation that enacted this reform.  In 1994, the ATRA created a publication that displayed the status of each State law on medical liability.  This publication has been updated several times since that time, and it is currently available on the ATRA Web site. 

McCullough, Campbell & Lane is a large general practice law firm located in Chicago with a specialty in insurance law, and this firm publishes a compendium of all legislation relating to medical malpractice for each state.  This compendium is available on the McCullough, Campbell & Lane Web site (http://www.mcandl.com/states.html).

These data sources were used to ascertain the date of the legislation enacting state laws that limit damage awards in medical malpractice cases (Table 1A).  Five States enacted legislation capping awards before 1985, and the dummy variable for the cap variable in our 1985 data set was set equal to 1 for each of these five States.  Each of these laws was enacted in 1975 or 1976 in response to the medical malpractice crisis in the early 1970s. 

Ten States enacted laws implementing damage caps in malpractice cases in 1985 or 1986 in response to the medical malpractice crisis in the early 1980s.  The 1986 Alaska law was exceptional among these laws because it excluded cases involving physical impairment or severe disfigurement, and it is uncertain how many malpractice cases were subject to this exclusion.  In any event, we excluded Alaska from our analyses because of this ambiguity and because the empirical relationship between factors affecting physician decisions whether or not to locate in Alaska is likely to be quite different from this relationship for other States.  The dummy variable for the cap variable in our 1990 data set was set equal to 1 for each of the nine States (excluding Alaska) that adopted caps in 1985 or 1986. 

Two States implemented legislation capping damages in 1988, one in 1990, and two in 1995.  Thus, we set the dummy variable indicating the existence of a law limiting damage awards to 1 for the 19 States with such a law (excluding Alaska) in our 1995 data set and we set this variable equal to 1 for the same 19 States in our 2000 data set (access Table 1A for a list of the States).

Data on State characteristics for the years 1980, 1990, 1995, and 2000 are used in our model, and these data were obtained from various issues of the Statistical Abstract of the United States.  The following paragraphs define each variable and indicate the underlying data source. 

The variable population per square mile of land area was derived from data on each State's population and its number of square miles as provided by the U.S. Census Bureau (U.S. Department of Commerce).36 The U.S. Census Bureau issues State population estimates that are updated annually and are based on the preceding decennial census as well as other more limited surveys. Data on proportion of the population 65 years or older for each State were obtained from the U.S. Census Bureau.

Data on State unemployment rates were obtained from the U.S. Department of Labor's Current Population Survey (CPS).37   The CPS is a monthly, random, national survey of the noninstitutionalized population in the United States.  About 50,000 households are sampled each month.

Data on mean State per capita personal income were obtained from the various issues of the Survey of Current Business, a publication of the Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Department of Commerce. 

Data on the proportion of the State domestic product attributable to farm income also were obtained from reports issued by the U.S. Department of Commerce.38 Farm income comprises cash receipts from the marketing of crops and livestock as well as government payments made directly to farmers for farm-related activities. 

Information about the number of hospital beds in each State was obtained from data published by the American Hospital Association (AHA).39 The AHA provides information about the number of hospital beds in non-Federal, short-term community hospitals in each State that are acceptable for registration with AHA. 

The data in our county analyses were obtained from the 2002 Area Resource File. The ARF is maintained by Quality Resource Systems, Inc., under contract with the Bureau of Health Professions, Health Resources and Services Administration, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services. The ARF is a county database that includes statistics on health facilities, health professions, economic activity, and health training programs. Just as in the Statistical Abstract of the United States, the ARF uses existing data sources. Indeed, in many instances, the Statistical Abstract of the Unites States and the ARF use the same underlying source of data.

The dependent variable in both our State-level and county-level analyses is the number of active, non-Federal physicians per 100,000 civilians residing in each State. Both the Statistical Abstract of the Unites States and the ARF obtain the number of active, non-Federal physicians from the AMA.40 AMA publications contain information about the professional and individual characteristics of all practicing physicians. 

Data on the population in each county are based on publications of the U.S. Bureau of the Census.  Data on births in each county were obtained from the National Center for Health Statistics, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC), and data on the unemployment rate in each county were provided by the U.S. Department of Labor.

Return to Contents
Proceed to Next Section

 

AHRQAdvancing Excellence in Health Care