Before the Commonwealth of Massachusetts Department of
Telecommunications and Energy

Boston, Massachusetts

Order on Standards of Conduct                                                                                                                                                         DTE 97-96

Comment of the Staff of the
Bureau of Economics
of the Federal Trade Commission(1)

October 8, 1998

I. Introduction and Summary

The staff of the Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) appreciates this opportunity to respond to the invitation of the Commonwealth of Massachusetts Department of Telecommunications and Energy (MDTE) to comment on the MDTE's rules governing relationships between regulated electric utilities and their affiliated entities operating in unregulated markets.

The FTC is an independent administrative agency responsible for maintaining competition and safeguarding the interests of consumers. The staff of the FTC often analyzes regulatory or legislative proposals that may affect competition or the efficiency of the economy. In the course of this work, as well as in antitrust research, investigation, and litigation, the staff applies established principles and recent developments in economic theory and empirical analysis to competition issues.

The staff of the FTC has a longstanding interest in regulation and competition in energy markets, including proposals to reform regulation of the natural gas and electric power industries. The staff has submitted numerous comments concerning these issues at both the federal and state levels.(3) Moreover, the FTC has reviewed proposed mergers involving electric and gas utility companies.

The MDTE has invited the staff of the FTC's Bureau of Economics to comment on the MDTE's Order on Standards of Conduct (DTE 97-96) issued on May 29, 1998. The MDTE adopted these rules "to address concerns regarding the possible inappropriate use of distribution company assets and resources on behalf of . . . non-energy-related affiliates, and also to further the policy goal of full and fair competition in other industries subject to the jurisdiction of the Department. . . ."(4)

First, Sections II through IV of our comment discuss the fundamental trade-offs between preventing discriminatory behavior by the parent utility and preserving economies of vertical integration with its affiliates. We evaluate the potential costs and benefits of behavioral unbundling versus structural separation of distribution companies from their affiliates.(5) We conclude that permitting utilities to own affiliates, but requiring that the affiliates be operated independently, is a reasonable initial approach. The MDTE, however, may wish to reevaluate the trade-offs and alternatives at a specified date in the future, based on its experience during the interim.

Second, the MDTE has created behavioral rules prohibiting favoritism or discrimination in transactions between regulated parent utilities and their unregulated affiliates. As discussed in Section V, the MDTE may wish to add a "market-like" institution to govern transactions between parent utilities and their affiliates, so that a regulated utility's purchases from unregulated affiliates would be limited to contracts won through an objective bidding process in which a third party evaluates the bids. This arrangement is likely to allow an affiliate to participate in unregulated markets yet preserve any significant vertical economies with the parent utility. Experience in other settings suggests that this bidding arrangement can work if there is confidence in the objectivity of the bid evaluation process.

Third, the MDTE rules permit an affiliate to use the corporate name or logo of the regulated parent firm with the proviso that such use be accompanied by a disclaimer. Section VI notes that the MDTE may wish to conduct consumer testing to assure itself that such a disclaimer is sufficient to avoid consumer deception. It may be difficult to establish an effective disclaimer.

Fourth, the MDTE's explanatory statement accompanying its rules relies, in part, on enforcement of the Federal antitrust laws to remedy existing market power. The Federal antitrust laws were developed to prevent increases in market power through mergers or unfair forms of competition. The analysis of horizontal mergers under the guidelines developed by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission(6) does not focus on detecting or measuring market power that either may exist in the market or is not being protected or enhanced by unfair methods of competition. As we discuss in Section VII, the MDTE may wish to reexamine whether to address existing market power in its affiliate rules.

II. Benefits and Costs of Separating a Utility from Its Affiliates

The MDTE is justifiably concerned about effects on consumers and competition of potential discrimination and cross-subsidization in transactions between regulated distribution utilities and their unregulated affiliates providing retail electric and gas services.(7) These concerns are increasing as states implement regulatory reform in the electric industry by requiring vertically integrated monopolies to unbundle various services. The basic policy issue concerns how to balance the expected benefits and costs of separating regulated utilities from their unregulated affiliates. The Public Utility Commission of Texas has noted that this tradeoff should be analyzed with a recognition of utilities' continuing incentives:

[T]here is a strong likelihood that a utility will favor its affiliates where these affiliates are providing services in competition with other, non-affiliated entities. . . . [In addition,] there is a strong incentive for regulated utilities or their holding companies to subsidize their competitive activity with revenues or intangible benefits derived from their regulated monopoly businesses. . . . Finally, . . . current regulations . . . are not adequate to prevent or discourage [this] anticompetitive behavior. . . . However, the Commission is aware that efficient competition is fostered by encouraging the participation of many qualified participants, including unregulated affiliates.(8)

The potential benefits to consumers from preventing discriminatory transactions and cross-subsidization between regulated distribution utilities and their unregulated affiliates can take several forms. First, discrimination and cross-subsidization may artificially increase the costs of the regulated utility as costs incurred for the benefit of the affiliate are shifted to the regulated firm. Under a rate-of-return regulatory regime, higher costs will result in increased prices in the regulated market. Second, such conduct may increase costs in unregulated markets by displacing innovative, lower-cost suppliers and entrants with a higher-cost affiliate of the local regulated distribution utility. Third, this displacement also may eliminate or reduce the process and product innovations that the displaced firms would have provided to consumers.

On the other hand, unbundling can impose costs on consumers in the form of lost economies of vertical integration and forgone economies of scale or scope.(9) These lost economies translate into higher costs and higher prices in either the regulated or unregulated markets. In addition, participation by affiliates may in itself increase competition in relevant markets.

In weighing the trade-offs between preventing discrimination and fostering economies of vertical integration, it is important to keep in mind that these questions arise in a broader context of introducing competition into a very large industry with widespread effects on local economies as well as the national economy. For competition to take hold quickly and effectively in these formerly regulated markets, it may be particularly important to dispel potential entrants' perceptions that the incumbent distribution firms will manipulate rules and mislead regulators to the disadvantage of new competitors.

This perception issue gains urgency to the extent that entry may be less costly when competition is being introduced publicly in the electricity industry because consumers and businesses are likely to be more aware of and interested in new choices. Conversely, entry may be more costly and less likely in the long run if an incumbent retains incentives to increase the risks of entrants into markets served by the incumbent's affiliates. These broader concerns about entry are not as relevant to state regulators when an affiliate is operating in competitive markets that are less closely related to the markets supplied by the regulated incumbent. Accordingly, the need to address (and reduce) the perception of potential discrimination and cross-subsidization may be greatest when competition is just getting underway.

III. Initial Assessment of Efficiencies Due to Vertical Integration

Before going forward with its current behavioral rules, the MDTE may wish to assess whether significant existing or prospective economies of vertical integration will be lost when affiliates are operated independently. Such an assessment could alleviate some uncertainty about the costs and benefits of different policy options. If economies of vertical integration are minimal, divestiture at the outset of regulatory reform may be more appropriate than applying the behavioral rules. Conversely, if economies of vertical integration are substantial, the MDTE may wish to consider whether any type of separation of a utility from its affiliates is likely to yield net benefits. Recent empirical evidence suggests that economies of vertical integration in the electric industry may be material, but that they vary considerably in different circumstances and may be realized through alternative organizational arrangements.(10) Given this evidence, it seems reasonable to assume initially that vertical integration produces at least modest economies.

IV. Benefits and Costs of Potential Remedies for Market Power

As a general proposition, we have found that structural remedies to address market power, such as divestiture in merger cases, are the most effective and require the least amount of subsequent monitoring by government agencies. The effectiveness of structural remedies stems from the fact that they directly alter incentives. Divestiture, however, may be costly in terms of both transaction costs and irreversibility.

Behavioral remedies, in contrast, leave incentives for discriminatory behavior in place. They also are likely to impose a substantial burden on government agencies to monitor subsequent conduct. Because behavioral rules leave incentives to discriminate in place, active monitoring and enforcement of such rules are essential if the rules are to appreciably curtail discrimination.(11)

In two comments to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC), we discussed this type of trade-off and recommended alternative approaches that appeared less costly than divestiture. Each approach sought to capture the benefits of structural remedies while retaining economies of vertical integration and allowing additional firms (the affiliates) to participate in unregulated markets. In 1987, when the industry undergoing deregulation was natural gas pipelines, we suggested that FERC prohibit marketing firms from using their affiliated natural gas pipelines, but we did not recommend vertical divestiture or rate regulation.(12) In 1995, we suggested that FERC promote ISOs to control the regional electric transmission grids as an alternative either to ordering divestiture of transmission lines or to relying solely on open access rules to promote competition in electric generation markets.(13)

Even if the MDTE determines that its affiliate rules are likely to preserve significant economies of vertical integration without harming competition, the MDTE may nonetheless choose to specify a future date to review whether these projected economies are realized.(14) At that time, it may be appropriate for the MDTE to review the experience of other jurisdictions that have prescribed different kinds of affiliate rules.(15) The MDTE may wish to move to a divestiture policy after its subsequent policy review if (1) the existing rules prove inadequate to prevent discriminatory conduct or cross-subsidization by affiliates or parent utilities (or are too costly to enforce), and (2) the benefits of preventing such conduct outweigh the costs of forgone economies of vertical integration.

V. Limits on Transactions Between Utilities and Their Affiliates

The MDTE has established certain behavioral rules to discourage discrimination in transactions between regulated utilities and their unregulated affiliates. As discussed above, we have significant reservations about the effectiveness of relying exclusively on behavioral rules. If the scale, scope, or vertical integration economies of affiliation are substantial and can be realized even in the presence of functional unbundling, the MDTE may wish to strengthen its approach by requiring the affiliates to operate independently, on a bid-based, arm's-length basis. For example, the MDTE may wish to require that the bulk of regulated utility purchases from unregulated affiliates be restricted to contracts won through an objective bidding process in which a third party evaluates the bids.

A critical element of workable bidding systems is the perceived and actual objectivity of the bid evaluation process. The system must be perceived as objective in order to attract bidders. Potential bidders, other than affiliates, may be unwilling to incur the costs of making a bid if the system is perceived as biased in favor of affiliates. The system must also be objective in fact in order to avoid raising costs for customers of the regulated utility. The use of third-party evaluations of the bids is one technique for achieving such objectivity.(16)

A question addressed in the MDTE's Order is whether non-energy affiliates would be covered by the antidiscrimination rules of the MDTE.(17) The MDTE concluded that electric distribution company affiliates have no ". . . inherent market power in non-energy-related markets. . . ." We generally agree. The MDTE also concluded that cross-subsidization can be addressed adequately through appropriate transfer pricing rules. We are less sanguine about this conclusion, as discussed below in Section VI. In our view, the argument for arm's-length transactions may apply equally well to energy-related and non-energy-related affiliates. Our concerns about the effectiveness of rules against cross-subsidization apply equally to energy-related and non-energy-related affiliates.

The MDTE has proposed that asset transfers from the parent distribution utility to an affiliate be subject to particular price bounds to assure that ratepayers do not unfairly subsidize the activities of the affiliate.(18) This proposal raises issues similar to determining the value of assets in assessing stranded costs. Just as the MDTE has determined that the market is the best gauge to determine the value of generating assets in a stranded cost assessment,(19) it also may wish to use actual market values, rather than a band of prices, for asset transfers. The arm's-length bid process discussed above is an example of a method to establish actual market values.

VI. Benefits and Costs of Allowing Affiliates to Use the Parent Distribution Firm's Logo

In evaluating its new rules, the MDTE may wish to compare the benefits and costs of allowing affiliates of regulated distribution firms to use the corporate logo of the distribution firm. One benefit of such use may be to reduce prices in the competitive markets served by affiliates. With access to the parent company's logo, the affiliate is likely to have lower marketing costs that may be passed along to consumers in a competitive market.(20) The lower prices of the affiliate may encourage other firms serving this market to charge lower prices as well, resulting in lower prices for the market as a whole.(21) If consumers accurately perceive the implications of an affiliate's use of the parent utility's logo,(22) a second prospective benefit may be reduced search costs for consumers.

On the cost side, we have identified two potential concerns about the use of logos by affiliates: deception of consumers and cross-subsidization.

(1) Potential Deception: Massachusetts is concerned about the effects on consumers and competition of unrestricted use by unregulated affiliates of the logo of the regulated distribution firm. Harm to consumers and competition may occur if elements of the reputation of the regulated firm are not applicable to the unregulated affiliate, but consumers believe that they are applicable when the unregulated affiliate uses the parent utility's logo.(23) For example, an element of a parent firm's reputation might be the credibility of its pledges of high-quality service that are backed by the parent's financial stability as a government-franchised monopoly. If a consumer imputed this same credibility to an affiliate's promises of high-quality service because of its use of the parent's logo, when in fact the affiliate did not have access to the revenues of the monopoly franchise, the consumer could be injured if the affiliate was unable to fulfill its promises in the way the consumer expected.(24) Under such circumstances, the use of the logo by the unregulated affiliate could harm consumers and competition in much the same way as deceptive advertising.

Deceptive advertising is prohibited under Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act.(25) The FTC generally considers advertising deceptive if at least a substantial minority of consumers acting reasonably takes a particular message from an advertisement, and if that message is likely to mislead consumers to their detriment.(26)

Thus, when considering the effect of an affiliate's use of the parent utility's logo, the FTC would consider consumers' impressions about the relationship between the utility and the affiliate and whether those impressions would be likely to affect purchase decisions. If use of the utility's logo implies to consumers that the relationship between the utility and the affiliate is different from what it really is -- an attribute that consumers care about -- such use of the logo could be considered deceptive.

We suggest that the MDTE evaluate the alternatives related to this issue by focusing on the impression that consumers are likely to have under a particular policy alternative, and whether that impression would be accurate. For example, it may be difficult to develop disclaimers as proposed by the MDTE that are simultaneously sufficient to avoid deception and succinct enough not to make impractical the unregulated affiliates' use of the regulated parent utility's logo. Consumer research designed to investigate the effects of several alternative policies on consumers may be the most effective approach.(27) If research reveals that consumers are harmed by this deception, the MDTE may wish to restrict further an affiliate's use of the parent's logo.

(2) Potential Cross-subsidization and the Use of the Parent Utility's Logo: Although some forms of cross-subsidization may be effectively addressed by transfer pricing rules,(28) other forms may be more difficult to assess. Cross-subsidization could take the form of cost-shifting among inputs used for both regulated and unregulated products, such as the use of a corporate logo in marketing the affiliate's products and services as well as the regulated parent utility's products and services. Costs of shared inputs could be assigned in a biased manner (i.e., with additional costs assigned to the regulated side of the business) so that the regulated entity can justify higher rates. This biased assignment of costs, which is often difficult for regulators to detect and remedy, distorts competition and produces inefficiencies in the unregulated business as well.

The risk of failing to detect anticompetitive cross-subsidization is heightened if (1) the reputation of the regulated parent utility is effectively embodied or represented by its logo; (2) the regulated parent firm can improve its reputation by incurring costs of the type that regulators would traditionally include in the rate base of the regulated firm; and (3) the unregulated affiliate can enhance its own reputation among consumers by using the logo of the regulated parent firm, even if elements of the regulated firm's reputation do not apply to the affiliate. When these factors are present, a regulated incumbent will have a heightened incentive to overinvest in reputation-building because it can expect to incorporate a greater share of these investments into its rate base than if the assets were not shared with the affiliate. Moreover, the affiliate would realize additional profits from its increased sales in the unregulated market. The principal obstacle to deterring this conduct is that it may be extraordinarily difficult to distinguish competitive from anticompetitive levels of investment in reputation-building. Harm to competition and to consumers may result from such overinvestment and subsequent cross-subsidization.

Harm to competition may occur because the unregulated affiliate's access to the logo of its regulated parent gives it a cost advantage that otherwise equally efficient competitors cannot match. The anticompetitive results may include (1) higher-than-necessary average operating (i.e., non-logo-related) costs for the industry and higher prices for consumers due to the continued operation of the affiliate, which can survive with higher-than-necessary costs due to the cross-subsidization; (2) greater market concentration and less competition than would occur absent the cross-subsidization;(29) and (3) discouragement of potential entry that likely would have occurred absent the cross-subsidization, including entry involving innovative products and production processes. If the MDTE finds this concern to be important, it may wish to recognize that transfer pricing rules may not address all of the significant forms of cross-subsidization, and thus may wish to consider ordering the divestiture of unregulated affiliates.

If the MDTE determines upon more detailed study that substantial economies of vertical integration cannot be realized without allowing affiliates to use the logos of their regulated parent utilities, the MDTE may wish to consider an alternative policy of requiring that the affiliate (and any other firms granted the right to use the logo) pay the parent for the right to use the logo.(30) Because the logo is an asset, use of the logo by other firms, including affiliates, represents an asset transfer from the parent firm, and the MDTE may wish to treat it like other asset transfers.(31) In order to avoid cross-subsidization in such a transaction, the use of the parent logo must be fairly evaluated. As discussed in Section V, a bid-based, arm's-length approach may be an effective method of reaching a fair valuation.

VII. Reach of the Federal Antitrust Laws

In some instances, the MDTE implies that antitrust enforcement can be relied upon to address issues of existing market power.(32) Although the DOJ/FTC Merger Guidelines provide a firm foundation for analyzing changes in prospective market power resulting from a proposed merger, the analysis does not focus on detecting or measuring market power that may already exist in the market. Further, antitrust enforcement is focused on anticompetitive mergers and unfair methods of competition. From an antitrust perspective, a firm that lawfully acquired market power does not commit an antitrust offense merely by exercising that power unless, for example, it engages in unfair methods of competition to protect that power. Consequently, antitrust enforcement may not be able to remedy such market power as a market moves from locally regulated monopolies to competition. The MDTE may wish to examine these instances to assess whether its rules are adequate in light of the limited reach of the Federal antitrust laws.

VIII. Conclusion

The MDTE has established a set of rules designed to strike a balance between preventing discriminatory conduct by utilities and their affiliates and preserving possible economies of vertical integration. These rules may be reasonably strengthened by including bidding rules for transactions between regulated utilities and their unregulated affiliates and, as so strengthened, appear to constitute a reasonable initial approach if there are both (1) significant economies of vertical integration between regulated utilities and their affiliates operating in unregulated markets, and (2) net benefits to be gained from separating regulated utilities and their unregulated affiliates. If this is the case, the MDTE may wish to set a date to reevaluate the adequacy of the rules it has adopted, with a view to moving to full divestiture if the rules have not prevented discrimination and cross-subsidization, or have proven very costly to enforce effectively. In the area of consumer protection, the MDTE may wish to adopt rules on advertising by affiliates that are consistent with FTC law on deceptive advertising. The MDTE may also wish to evaluate incentives to overinvest in reputation-building if affiliates are allowed to use the parent firm's logo. Finally, the MDTE may wish to review how limits on the scope of antitrust enforcement affect its assessment of existing market power conditions.

Respectfully submitted,

________________________
Jonathan B. Baker, Director
John C. Hilke, Electricity Project Coordinator
Bureau of Economics
Federal Trade Commission

October 8, 1998

1. This comment represents the views of the staff of the Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade Commission. They are not necessarily the views of the Federal Trade Commission or any individual Commissioner.

2. This comment represents the views of the staff of the Bureau of Economics of the Federal Trade Commission. They are not necessarily the views of the Federal Trade Commission or any individual Commissioner. Inquiries regarding this comment should be directed to John C. Hilke (303-844-3565).

3. The staff of the FTC has submitted comments to various state agencies, including the Public Utilities Commission of Nevada, LCB File No. R087-98, PUCN Docket No. 97-5034 (affiliate rules) (Sept. 22, 1998); Louisiana Public Service Commission, Docket No. U-21453 (stranded costs) (Aug. 7, 1998); Michigan Public Service Commission, Case No. U-11290 (electric restructuring) (Aug. 7, 1998); West Virginia Public Service Commission, Case No. 98-0452-E-GI (electric restructuring) (July 15, 1998); Commonwealth of Virginia, Joint Subcommittee Studying Electric Industry Restructuring, SJR-91 (July 9, 1998); Public Utility Commission of Texas, Project Number 17549 (affiliate transactions) (June 19, 1998); Maine Department of the Attorney General and Public Utilities Commission, "Interim Report on Market Power in Electricity" (May 29, 1998); Louisiana Public Service Commission, Docket No. U-21453 (market power) (May 15, 1998); California Public Utilities Commission, Docket Nos. R.94-04-031 and I.94-04-032 (electric industry restructuring)(Aug. 23, 1995); and South Carolina Legislative Audit Council (section on foreign experience in electric industry restructuring) (Feb. 28, 1994). The staff of the FTC has commented to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) on electric power regulation in Docket RM98-4-000 (Sept. 11, 1998); Docket No. PL98-5-000 (May 1, 1998); Docket Nos. ER97-237-000 and ER97-1079-000 (Feb. 6, 1998); Docket No. RM96-6-000 (May 7, 1996); Docket Nos. RM95-8-000 and RM94-7-001 (Aug. 7, 1995) (Open Access Comment). In addition, the FTC staff has commented to FERC about natural gas deregulation in Docket No. RM88-13-000 (capacity brokering) (1988); Docket No. RM87-5-000 alleged anticompetitive practices of pipeline marketing affiliates (1987) (Pipeline Comment); and Docket No. RM85-1-000 (pipeline regulation after partial wellhead decontrol) (1985).

4. MDTE Order at 3.

5. Behavioral unbundling rules proscribe specific behavior between a parent and its affiliate, but do not remove the parent's profit incentives to engage in such behavior.

6. U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines, issued April 2, 1992, revised April 8, 1997.

7. Under fully implemented retail competition, it is expected that both generation and final sales to end users (such as residential consumers, businesses, schools, etc.) will operate competitively with no price regulation. Meanwhile, distribution and transmission services are likely to remain regulated, given current technology. The formerly regulated local monopoly suppliers generally will be required to unbundle their services when retail competition is initiated. (An exception may occur if the state designates the traditional vertically integrated utility as the "supplier of last resort" to serve customers who do not select a competitive supplier.) To accomplish this unbundling, a traditional utility that is allowed by law or regulation to retain ownership of all its previous assets could, for example, elect to establish separate affiliates that would compete in (1) generating electricity (competing with other generators), and (2) selling electricity to consumers (competing with power marketers, independent power producers, utilities from nearby geographic areas, or the electricity supply pool associated with an Independent System Operator (ISO)). The utility also could establish unregulated affiliates in other industries or in other geographic markets in the electric industry.

8. Promulgation of New Rules Governing Activities Between Affiliates, Public Utility Commission of Texas, Project No. 17459, 23 Tex. Reg. 5294 (May 22, 1998).

9. Economies of vertical integration occur when a single firm's performance of activities at two or more stages of production yields lower average costs. Economies of scale are present if, when all inputs are adjusted optimally, average costs decline as output increases within a firm. Economies of scope are present if average costs decline when two or more products are produced by the same firm. See Jean Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization 16-21, 288 (1989).

10. See John E. Kwoka, Jr., Power Structure: Ownership, Integration, and Competition in the U.S. Electricity Industry (1996).

11. The enforcement of the MDTE's behavioral rules may be complicated by various state regulatory schemes that impose different behavioral rules on affiliates of distribution utilities operating in more than one state.

12. Pipeline Comment, supra note 2.

13. Open Access Comment, supra note 2. Unbundling through an ISO is termed "operational unbundling." Unbundling through behavioral rules against discrimination is termed "functional unbundling." Both divestiture and operational unbundling are structural remedies that change incentives to discriminate.

14. One advantage of the MDTE's proposed approach to affiliate transactions (or of an augmented approach, as suggested in the next section) is that it will probably be less costly to revise than a policy of either ignoring potential discrimination or requiring full divestiture of affiliates.

15. Some experience already exists. For example, the California Public Utilities Commission fined Pacific Gas & Electric for failure to comply with affiliate advertising rules. See CPUC Press Release, Apr. 9, 1998 <www.cpuc.ca.gov/news>.

16. For example, Phoenix, Arizona has implemented a system of competitive bidding in which outside contractors compete against government departments for contracts to provide various city services. Before a city agency can submit a bid, however, the Office of the Comptroller, which is an independent entity, must certify that the bid is realistic. John C. Hilke, Competition in Government-Financed Services 16, 67-68 (1992).

17. Order, Section 12.B.

18. Order, Section 12.C.

19. Edison Electric Institute, 4 Retail Wheeling & Restructuring Report 65 (March 1998).

20. The incremental (marginal) cost of marketing to additional customers is likely to be lower if consumers are already familiar with the logo employed in the marketing effort, since little effort will be required to establish familiarity.

21. If the competing firms do not respond with lower prices, the affiliate likely will gain market share. If so, the average price in the market will be lower, even if competitors do not reduce their prices when the affiliate lowers prices, because of its lower marginal costs.

22. Consumers could view use of the parent utility's logo as a guarantee that the affiliate firm is not a fraudulent operator.

23. We use the term "logo" here to include the logo, name, and other elements used to identify the regulated utility.

24. Arguably, injury could occur even if the affiliate did not renege on its promises, because the actual expected value of the promise is less than the affiliate's use of the parent's logo led the consumer to believe.

25. 15 U.S.C. § 45.

26. See Federal Trade Commission's Policy Statement on Deception, letter to Hon. John D. Dingell, Chairman, Subcommittee on Oversight and Investigations, Committee on Energy and Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives (Oct. 14, 1983), appended to Cliffdale Associates, 103 F.T.C. 110 (1984).

27. Private parties may submit such evidence from privately funded research. The MDTE, however, may wish to be wary of testing performed on behalf of special interests, and may wish to take steps to ensure that the results represent useful indications of likely consumer impressions and behavior.

28. Transfer pricing rules typically forbid transactions between an unregulated affiliate and its regulated parent utility at prices that fall outside of specified limits. Commonly used boundaries include market prices, embedded costs, and book value.

29. If entry is difficult or delayed, market share gained through cross-subsidization also may have persistent market power effects even after the cross-subsidization has been discontinued.

30. Payments to the regulated distribution firm for use of its logo could reduce prices for distribution services by substituting for revenues that the firm otherwise would be authorized by the MDTE to collect through distribution charges.

31. In some situations, firms may sell the right to use a logo to independent entities, contingent upon conditions and restrictions placed on use of the logo.

32. Section III.B. refers to antitrust essential facilities cases as the source of an adequate remedy if a regulated utility or its unregulated affiliates hold essential facilities in an unregulated market. Section III.D. refers to Federal antitrust law for redress of existing market power of affiliates in non-regulated markets.


Last Modified: Monday, June 25, 2007